The Four Big Structural Forces Holding Back China's Economy
All thoughts is brought to you by Interactive Brokers.
IBKR charges margin loan rates from 5.83% to 6.83%.
Their clients can also earn extra income
by lending their fully paid shares of stock.
Join Interactive Brokers clients
from 200 plus countries and territories
to invest in stocks, options, futures, funds,
and bonds globally.
Minimize your costs to maximize your returns.
Rate subject to change.
Learn more at IBKR.com slash compare.
This is Barry Rittles here to tell you about another podcast
we think you'll love listening to, Masters in Business.
Join each week for an enlightening conversation
with some of the smartest people in investing and business.
Doing business in Europe, it's all about being local.
Stocks are way too cheap.
This is where you want to be.
I think life and markets are intertwined.
Subscribe to Masters in Business today.
On Apple, Spotify, or wherever you get your favorite podcast.
Hello, and welcome to another episode of the AdLocs podcast.
I'm Joe Weisenthal.
And I'm Tracy Alloway.
Tracy, very weak economic data out of China lately.
Yeah, to put it mildly.
I'm just starting very directly.
Now, the data has been very weak.
I have a collection of paraphrased headlines here.
Oh.
So we're recording.
So we're recording.
We're recording.
We're recording.
We're recording.
We're recording.
We're recording.
So we're recording this on August 16th.
And we just saw an emergency rate cut from China.
They also announced that they would stop publishing the urban youth
unemployment rate, which is never a good sign.
When you just, when you just announce that a certain data point
that people have been tracking for years, suddenly will not be
publishing more yet.
Exactly.
And a particularly politically sensitive data point too.
Retail sales are coming in extremely weak.
So rising less than 3% a year, they
used to be in double digits.
We have deflation setting in, which is something
we spoke about on the episode we did with Richard Koo.
Manufacturing is contracting.
Exports are falling.
The UN is dropping against the dollar bank loans
at a 14 year low last month.
You came prepared, Tracy.
I did.
Yeah, I know it's surprising.
But I did actually.
I did have no surprise.
I've just impressed.
I did actually put together the data points
because they're so startling.
And again, if you compare it with all the excitement
from earlier in the year about China reopening
the end of COVID-0, there was this expectation
that China was going to end up being a positive catalyst
for global growth this year.
And instead, we are potentially seeing the exact opposite.
Yeah, you bring up a good point.
I think one of the theories is that there
would be this big inflationary impulse globally
from the China reopening, demand for steel, demand
for various metals, obviously demand for oil and gasoline.
And there has been this pretty mild mediocre reopening.
It hasn't had that global shockwaves.
If anything, people are talking about exporting deflation
or disinflation.
And then on top of all of the economic weakness
that you bring up, there's also the financial market
weakness.
So there was just a story today about one
of the companies that sell some of these wealth management
products, missing payments.
There's obviously, I think, it's a country card.
Country card.
A big developer running into a lot of trouble similar,
similar to the weakness we've seen in China Evergrande.
So to your point, though, just this sort of slew
of negative headlines.
Well, also, I think clearly there is concern
that if you get real economic weakness in China,
that could lead to something bad for the global economy,
just in terms of real business activity.
But I think there's also this financial channel
that is probably the one that's likely
to be the most problematic.
So if you think about China as, in many ways,
a giant hoarder of financial assets,
the big question now is, what are they
going to do with those financial assets?
Do they have to, for instance, start selling off
some FX reserves in order to support the UN?
Are they maybe going to buy fewer US treasuries?
So I think that is definitely one aspect of this
that is really worth exploring.
So many interesting elements right now, we have,
so we have to dive deeper into what is going on right now
with the Chinese economy and what types of policy responses
we might get or we might not get.
There's a, I always see, you know,
there's like a furious debate always on Twitter.
It's like, why don't they just,
why doesn't the government just give more money
to households sort of like the Richard Kuh conversation,
the sort of, you know, to get a boost domestic demand?
What's the reluctance to do that?
Like all these sort of different questions.
So I think we really need to dive into them further.
Let's do it.
Well, I'm very excited because I think we have
the perfect guest to discuss this.
We are going to be speaking with Songwen Zoe Liu.
She is the Maurice Greenberg Fellow
for China Studies at the CFR.
And she is also the author of a new book,
sovereign funds, how the Communist Party of China
finances its global ambitions.
Thank you so much for coming on, Adlots.
Thank you, Joe, and the Tracy for having me.
And I'm a big fan of the Adlots.
Very, very kind of you to say,
you know, why don't we just start off like super simply?
In your view, why hasn't China seen a more robust recovery
since the lifting of the COVID restrictions?
Well, I would say that, actually,
I have always met a contrary.
Oh, good.
I like this already.
I, you know, if, you know,
November last year, I put out a piece on the foreign policy,
basically made the argument to say that the zero COVID
is the least economic challenging problem
that President Xi Jinping was facing that day.
And even the party, in this case, it would be the party.
And even if the party decided to remove zero COVID policy
the next day, the economy won't rebound,
sustain a robust rebound very quickly.
And the reason comes from what I characterize
as the four Ds, demand that demographics
and decoupling, at that time it was decoupling
and now it's the risking.
This is great.
The four Ds.
I think it's like the four Ds of the apocalypse.
Yeah.
No, that's really, I feel like if you want to like
have your thing, that's like a really demand
and that demographics undecoupling, I'm writing these down.
So this is exactly what I wanted to ask you
because I remember even in 2018, 2019,
there were concerns and a lot of discussion
about a slowdown in China's economic growth.
And then COVID happened and we sort of forgot
about a lot of the structural issues
that we had been talking about.
And then lo and behold, in 2023,
it feels like a lot of these structural problems
are coming back to haunt the Chinese economy.
Can you dive a little bit further into what those issues are?
Yeah, sure.
I would argue that a lot of these structural problems,
exactly as you were describing Tracy,
it seemed that during COVID,
we were from both inside China and outside China,
we were overwhelmed by the sudden pause of the economy
because of the shutdown factories and all that.
And it seemed that temporarily,
the pause of the economy covered up
the structural problems that had been embedded
into the Chinese economic growth model.
And then once the party suddenly
acted the zero COVID policy,
given the consumption pattern
that we have observed here in America or in Europe,
people started to realize,
oh, okay, so this is a 1.4 billion market
and people are going to spend.
And that would be powerful and inflationary.
And, but short-term,
revengeful expenditure would not necessarily overcome
the long-term structural problems
that have attracted the Chinese economy
even just from GDP terms.
You know, we think about the Chinese economy.
There are different ways that you can argue
that the Chinese economy has picked.
I mean, I'm not necessarily that category,
but if we just a measure it from GDP perspective,
or in terms of export as a percentage of a GDP,
the Chinese economy already picked.
You know, China surpassed Germany back in 2010
to become the largest trading,
or the largest exporting economy in the world.
And it has, as it's a height,
export as a percentage of GDP was about 30%
and has since then plateaued and decreased
right now is about 20 something percent.
And if you think about GDP growth,
the double digit growth period already ended.
So from that perspective,
what do we actually observe?
Goes back to the four Ds.
The problem with demand is not necessarily at,
you know, I'm not talking about the ultimate demand,
I'm specifically talking about the household consumption
component of demand for a lumpier of the time.
You know, yes, you can,
we can make the argument to say household consumption
as a percentage contributing to the Chinese GDP is,
you know, it's about 40%.
Yeah, it has been low and, you know, global average.
I'm not even talking about, you know, the OECD level.
I'm talking about like global average.
It's about a 60% of GDP,
whereas China is 40%.
We can make the argument to say,
well, the household consumption has been a drag
on the Chinese economy.
However, up until 2012, by the end of 2012,
actually household consumption's contribution to GDP growth,
at least has been on an upward projection.
Yeah, other word of the growth of household consumption
has been positive.
You know, you see Chinese people do discretionary vacations
and all that, but that has changed since 2000.
13.
And if we just a stretch it in between
President Xi Jinping's two-term,
the second term was either worse than the first term.
So let's go further into that.
A, why has it gotten worse?
And then B, you know, there's all this talk.
It's like, why don't they just do household stimulus?
Or some version of that.
And people are sort of bemused.
Maybe it's the word it's like,
oh, why isn't the Communist Party
more willing to extend support directly to the people
and rebalancing things?
A, why did it get worse?
But why is there this reluctant to do something
like what we did in the US,
just sort of print money and give it to people?
You know, Joe, that's an excellent, excellent question.
You make me think about the Y aspect of it, right?
So fundamentally, there are, I would argue that
there are two aspects of why there has been
a decreasing household consumption.
The first one is, obviously,
you can empirically observe from the data.
There has been a decline in household income growth.
And household income growth up until President Xi Jinping,
before President Xi Jinping came to power,
household growth was,
income growth was significantly faster
than after he came to power.
And he's, again, he's the second term
was worse on average than his first term.
So that's one aspect in terms of income,
household income growth.
And then the second aspect of it
would be household balance sheet DTO raileration.
And a lot of these comes down to housing market,
a property value depreciation
because of control on real estate policies and all that.
Now, the reason why there has been a reluctant
in terms of a stimulus,
basically provide a stimulus checks to Chinese household,
is not that Chinese economists
have not thought about that option.
You actually do, see people do that
on Chinese social media when they realize that,
oh, you know what, my cousins in America,
they just become just a lineup
or waiting in their house
and then mail would come in and get, you know,
a stimulus check, you know,
some students were even getting stimulus check.
And then the problem becomes,
well, historically there has not been
this kind of a precedent,
but no precedent does not necessarily
stop the government from inventing one, right?
And the deeper problem I would argue
is the politics.
The politics simply would not necessarily work.
Part of that is because,
empowering, this is probably deeper
in the Chinese political philosophy in the sense that,
well, you know, it's a,
depending upon which political scientists
or political economists you are talking to,
some people would say, oh, you know,
Chinese system is authoritarian capitalism
or fragmented capitalism or fragmented authoritarianism
and things like that.
But fundamentally, what do we observe?
Is that the Chinese economic growth model
has been viewed upon financial repression
and at the center of the financial repression
are the Chinese banks and who controls the bank
is essentially the Chinese government led
by the Chinese Communist Party.
In other word, the Chinese Communist Party
has always been at the center of a capital allocation
and by empowering the household
or for that matter, the private sector,
it basically dilute or potentially remove their relevancy.
Interesting.
This is exactly what I wanted to ask you
and I just did a thread on Twitter
that made a similar point.
But how much of this is a political economy problem
in the sense that both on the business side
and the consumption side where we've seen
the Communist Party be sort of, well,
be controlling in many ways.
So for instance, on private business,
we've had the property crackdown,
the tech sector crackdown,
and that would apparently seem to perhaps
make people more reluctant to do their own startups
and things like that.
And then on the household side,
it does feel like you have a reluctance from the party
to sort of empower the individual
at the risk of losing some of their own power
and perhaps the collective power.
I am a political economist,
so I would argue.
The answer is yes.
Yes.
You are right, Tracy.
And from a intellectual perspective,
I do think this is a political economy problem
because if you look at the history
of the Chinese economic growth since 1949,
it's not a data that economy has never experienced shocks.
Actually, the Chinese system experienced a lot of shocks
from even in the 1950s,
you experienced the Chinese economy experienced
the grip leap forward.
And when the communist took over,
they also destroyed a lot of banking systems
in Shanghai and elsewhere established by the imperialist.
So, and then there was also cultural revolution and all that.
But then there is also the sudden stop of the cultural revolution.
In other words, the Chinese political economic system,
A, is not short of crisis
or for that matter, man made crisis.
And secondly, the Chinese economic system
was also not unfamiliar with sudden reverse
or sudden policy corrections.
And what that means for today,
that basically means the rapid growth
of the Chinese economy has fundamentally been led
by the government and the party
and is just a degree of party state involvement.
Now, if we think about the rise of Deng Xiaoping,
he crease monitor the rapid rise of China and all that.
But if we remember what actually made China,
the starting point of China's rapid growth
was not necessary.
Yes, it was 1978, the clear signal
that China is reforming and open up.
But then there was a Tiananmen
and the China was put under sanctions and all that.
And then 1992, he made this famous
southern tour, the Tiananmen, all those places.
And he gave a clear signal during his speech
when he was touring the southern part of China.
And I was just recently revisited his speech.
So I remember this is something that I learned very recently.
This I read his speech so many times.
So he cited this one example.
This rich person, apparently he was one of the,
if not the earliest, he was one of the
earliest Chinese entrepreneur to make 100 million yuan.
He was the founder of this sunflower seed company
called Shazguadze or Idiot sunflower seed.
When idiot sunflower seeds, yes, or food sunflower seeds,
Shazguadze.
And what's his name?
What's his name?
So at that time, out of jealousy
or some other reasons, there were some voices among Chinese people
or policymakers to say, this guy becomes so rich,
we need to take him down.
And he's in his speech.
Don't you think that I'm aware of this kind of recommendations?
But we cannot do that.
He's dragged it down.
And the reason he also explained why he,
the party cannot do that.
He said, if we punish to him,
that would ascend a terrible signal.
It would make people think that we changed
our policy of reform and open up.
And there are so many instances that we can do things
and make people think we changed our policies.
And we cannot do that.
So from his perspective, the big risk as he criticized it
is to make mistakes, to make people think
that we changed our policy.
Interactive brokers pay up to 4.83% on instantly available cash
in your brokerage account.
How much interest can your broker pay?
Interactive brokers can serve it
in prudent risk management uniquely positions them
to pay up to 4.83% on uninvested, instantly available cash
in your brokerage account.
The best informed investors choose interactive brokers,
rates subject to change.
Visit ibkr.com slash interest rates to learn more.
Access a vast selection of global fixed income securities
at interactive brokers bond marketplace.
Search their deep availability of over 1 million bonds globally.
ibkr has no markups or built-in spreads
and low fully transparent commissions on bonds.
ibkr displays the highest bids and lowest offers
received from the electronic venues they access.
In addition, clients can interact with each other
by placing bids and offers online to execute their trades.
Learn more at ibkr.com slash bonds.
This is Barry Rittles here to tell you about another podcast
we think you'll love listening to, Masters in Business.
Join each week for an enlightening conversation
with some of the smartest people in investing and business.
Doing business in Euro, it's all about being local.
Stocks are way too cheap.
This is where you want to be.
I think life and markets are intertwined.
Subscribe to Masters in Business today on Apple, Spotify,
or wherever you get your favorite podcast.
Can I ask sort of, I don't know, maybe it's a devil's advocate
question or I don't know how to characterize it.
But obviously there's this big household
debt overhang that you're talking about.
It seems from the outside and it seems from any comment.
There's like a pretty unhealthy real estate market
in terms of the level of speculation, the level of cost, et cetera.
It also seems as though the government would like to sort of find a way
to get out of that trap where it's not all about
not everything revolves around the cost of housing
or buying a new apartment.
Is there an argument to be made that stimulus direct to household
today under the current economic structure would just sort of
further fuel a real estate bubble or real estate demand
and that until the sort of domestic economy has shifted
in some way more such that it's not out of that dynamic
that it doesn't make sense to boost demand for those reasons.
First of all, I would say household demand for properties
or for housing in China is a perpetual decline for two reasons.
The first reason is that from empirical data,
we can observe that China's urbanization rate has picked.
And secondly, this goes back to one of the four days.
On the third day, demographics.
As of last year, Chinese population growth for the first time declined.
And there are some numbers saying that actually now India's population
is more than Chinese population.
So from the end, it's not just the population decline on its own,
it's not necessarily causing an immediate shock or negative shock
on housing demand, but it's actually the lower family
formation rate and the idea that people for whatever,
for cultural reasons is very expensive to get married
for fancy, you know, banquet and all that.
But you know, it's also very expensive to risk his in China,
especially in big cities.
So from that, those are the two structural reasons
why demand for housing is a perpetual decline in China.
Even if the government gives stimulus checks to the Chinese household
in the current mix of policy environment,
I would not necessarily be confident that the Chinese household
are going to be incentivized to spend
or be thinking that this is a good time to buy house.
And at the reason, there are two reasons.
The first reason is negative confidence shock.
And the second is a deflationary policy environment.
And the negative confidence, part of that comes from,
you know, people's material feeling that
their household balance sheet deteriorated
as being filled by the Chinese people as, well, you know,
I can you purely observe the value of my house went lower.
And yet I am still paying a lot of mortgage.
So you see, well, there is early mortgage payment,
which the banks are not happy about it.
And then on the other hand, as the Chinese GDP grow slows down,
you know, 3% last year despite record a high export last year.
And then on top of that, we see the move out
or the redistribution of global supply chains
and international multinationals become less,
you know, bullish about the Chinese market,
then, you know, high paying jobs there are less
the high paying jobs being created.
So Chinese people becomes like, well, wait a moment.
I don't think I'm going to make more money.
Therefore, they are not going to be incentivized to spend.
They are going to be more incentivized to save,
not because of good environment,
but because of lack of confidence.
And then deflationary policy environment is because
people are waiting.
Well, it seems that from the beginning of this year,
the government has put out so many policies
to incentivize people to spend
or for that matter support the housing market.
And there is this popular saying,
if you don't buy, if I don't buy,
the housing price per square meter next week
is going to be cheaper by 200 yen.
So everyone goes on strike, right?
To try to get a lower price.
I think this is such a good point
because historically, a lot of Chinese growth
has been driven by infrastructure investment and housing.
And it feels like infrastructure has kind of run its course.
China does have a lot of great infrastructure right now.
And at the same time,
housing the other sort of twin engine of growth,
there are a lot of doubts about it
as you just laid out perfectly.
I want to go back to something you said earlier.
I've never heard anyone phrase it quite like this,
but I think it's absolutely correct.
The idea that the Chinese economy
is sort of predicated on financial repression
and that introduces inherent limitations
in a situation like this.
Can you talk a little bit more
about how you see that working?
Sure.
The, you know, there are still many people talk
about financial repressions
and obviously people, you know,
Tracy, you are absolutely right.
A lot of infrastructure and housing
have been to the twine growth engine
for the Chinese economy
because the drive up aggregate demand
and they also drive up global commodity prices.
Right.
And I'm going to say that it's not
that China built too much infrastructure
or for the matter too much housing
is that they overbuilt it to the extent
that if population growth, population keep growing
or more international companies move into China
or there are more demand for factories
because of entrepreneurs and all that.
Growing supply, growing demand of the whole idea is,
this is the Chinese policy makers mentality.
As long as I build it, as long as I provide it,
the infrastructure, they will come, right?
But now the problem is,
international companies are not coming
for a variety of reasons
and a lot of the reasons goes back
to my quote about Deng Xiaoping.
Reason the Chinese leaders have simply made policy choices
and policy decisions, created a huge uncertainty
and a signal, even if they did not have the intention,
but at least from our observation,
they created the signal that perhaps
the Chinese government or the party
change their policies with regard to reform and open up.
So a lot of these boil down to, yes,
the party is still very much out of the center
of capital allocation in this whole idea
of financial repression.
This whole idea is to use high savings
that Chinese people tend to save
and this high savings is being channeled
through Chinese banking system
and the four biggest banks are state owned
and through lower depositors saving rate,
lower depositors rate,
the banks are able to lend cheaply
to support state owned enterprises
or channel credit to sectors that are prioritized
by the government.
And many people who follows China,
especially state owned enterprises,
they are familiar with this idea
of the government has these guidelines
or government guidelines for prioritized,
prioritized sectors every five years or so,
they would update it.
Right.
You know, so we've talked about household demand,
we've talked about debt,
we've talked about demographics,
there was actually a headline just yesterday
and Reuters, China's fertility rate,
drops to a record low 1.09 in 2016.
Oh, the one headline I left off on the list.
Yeah, you had to save one for me, I appreciate that,
which is so obviously still going,
you know, in the wrong direction.
And I want to talk about, you know,
the actual topic of your book,
but I think maybe there's the fourth D
in your fourth D framework, the decoupling.
And so obviously, I mean,
I think there's some like sort of intuitions,
like okay, like US or global multinationals,
maybe like less inclined to invest in China,
obviously the sort of growing trade tensions
that started under Trump and really have continued
or maybe even registered higher under Biden.
But how do you think of that word decoupling?
What does it mean to you?
Like how do you define it?
Honestly, I felt decoupling at the individual.
First of all, Joe, I appreciate that you're asking me,
you know, how I feel about it,
because people are very confused
about what is decoupling or what are talking about.
Do you risk it?
And there is actually no formal definition
about what they are at a personal level.
The moment during COVID, the moment I realized,
I cannot get on a plan from New York
to go back to Shanghai or Beijing.
For me, that is a sign of decoupling.
And right now, if I am correct,
there is still no direct flight between New York
and Beijing or Shanghai.
I didn't realize that.
And the flight, right now I think there are concrete policies
that, you know, concrete initiatives
in the aviation industry,
between US and China to increase the flight,
but it's still very below pre-pandemic level.
So what we are, we can't concretely observe
less and the less people to people communication.
And from economic sense, obviously,
or political economy sense decoupling, obviously, means,
or for that, you know, right now,
we are talking about the risk,
is very much a Western term,
if we view it from China or Chinese policy makers' perspective,
because this is the term that they condemn a lot.
You see, primarily in the summer Davos, in Tianjin,
that decoupling is a terrible idea,
is a false preface, and all that.
But decoupling, really,
I understand it from the perspective
of supply chain diversification.
The idea is really not about getting rid of China,
simply because China is on every part of your supply chain.
How could you possibly get rid of China, right?
But it's really about not being overly reliant
on your one simple supplier.
The whole idea of, you know,
you can't 101 used to be economy of scale,
but now economy of scale become a risk.
Huh, that's very well put.
Economies of scale becoming a risk.
So why don't speaking of scale,
why don't we talk about the sovereign wealth funds,
because when you look at the numbers
of something like CIC, I mean, they're massive,
with China, the numbers are almost always massive.
The accumulation of this wealth,
and the fact that it is held
by these public investment entities,
what does that mean in times like this?
China has, you know, billions,
possibly trillions of dollars worth of FX reserves.
I can't remember the exact number.
I think there's some debate over it now as well.
But could they tap some of those assets
to provide support in times of economic slowdown?
Tracy, that's an excellent point.
In times of economic slowdown,
I would say there are opportunities,
but in times of economic crisis,
they have done that before.
And actually, China's sovereign funds
initially was not created for geopolitical
or geoeconomic aspiration, power projection.
It was created out of crisis.
The very first time that the Chinese policymakers
used foreign exchange reserves
was to recapitalize the Chinese banks in the early 2000s.
When the major Chinese state-owned banks were
crippled by non-performing loans,
at that time, some of those banks were suffering
from non-performing loans as high as higher than 20% or 25%.
So by definition, they were, you know, non-solvent.
So at that time, they decided that they created
this special policy vehicle called Central Beijing
and used foreign exchange reserves
through Central Beijing to recapitalize these Chinese banks.
They have been quite accessible.
Therefore, when there were a few,
I think it's around 2015, if you remember correctly,
there was this Baoshang in Han Crisis.
It's another medium-sized bank crisis in China
and a lot of the confusion at that time people were saying
that, oh, you know, the Central Bank is going to take it over.
Actually, it's not the Central Bank.
It was the Central Beijing.
And now, when a lot of these bad loan managers
or bad debt managers or the so-called state-owned asset
management company, a lot of them are in trouble now.
And the idea is, I wouldn't be surprised.
You know, Beijing is going to step in and take them
on its balance sheet.
Because this is a well-established channel
that Central Beijing knows what to do it
and do it successfully.
Interactive brokers pay up to 4.83% on instantly available cash
in your brokerage account.
How much interest can your broker pay?
Interactive brokers can serve it of in prudent risk management
uniquely positions them to pay up to 4.83% on uninvested,
instantly available cash in your brokerage account.
The best informed investors choose interactive brokers,
rates subject to change, visit ibkr.com slash interest
rates to learn more.
Access a vast selection of global fixed income
securities at interactive brokers bond marketplace.
Search their deep availability of over 1 million bonds
globally.
ibkr has no markups or built-in spreads
and low fully transparent commissions on bonds.
ibkr displays the highest bids and lowest offers
received from the electronic venues they access.
In addition, clients can interact with each other
by placing bids and offers online to execute their trades.
Learn more at ibkr.com slash bonds.
This is Barry Rittles here to tell you about another podcast
we think you'll love listening to, Masters in Business.
Join each week for an enlightening conversation
with some of the smartest people in investing and business.
Doing business in Europe, it's all about being local.
Stocks are way too cheap.
This is where you want to be.
I think life and markets are intertwined.
Subscribe to Masters in Business today on Apple, Spotify,
or wherever you get your favorite podcast.
Stepping back further, I mean, you know,
a lot of sovereign wealth funds around the world
I associate with real commodity export countries.
So obviously the Norwegian sovereign wealth fund,
one of the biggest, the various golf sovereign wealth funds
and they tend to be in large part
about sort of currency stabilization
given the inherent volatility of GDP
and their export channel.
You mentioned, you know, this sort of origin of them
and the banking crisis.
Broadly speaking, what purpose do they serve
for China currently sitting beside the current economic weakness?
Sure.
In a joy, I appreciate that you mentioned
the origin of the sovereign funds, right?
And because a lot of these sovereign,
so-called sovereign wealth fund
in the entire universe of the sovereign wealth fund
as Tracey mentioned earlier, these funds are massive
and the Chinese funds are actually massive.
CIC alone, it managed more than 1.3 trillion asset,
which is larger than the size of Mexico's GDP.
And I think Mexico is like the world 17th largest economy
or something like that.
And China has more than that.
So broadly speaking, despite that, yes, you know,
originally these funds were the first time that China did it
was to solve a crisis and then as China's reserve accumulation
increase or at least, you know, Tracey was right,
there is a debate with regard to how we should think about
the size of China's foreign exchange asset.
But if we think about foreign exchange reserves
using IMF's narrow definition,
China's foreign exchange reserve was at one point
peak at $4 trillion, right now it's
plateaued around $3 trillion, slightly higher than $3 trillion.
And as China reserve accumulates faster and more,
the debate in terms of how to better manage
China's foreign exchange reserves started.
And after President Xi Jinping came to power
in particular, there has been a shift to strategically
use the foreign exchange reserves to serve certain foreign
policy agenda or to finance a certain government initiatives,
such as the creation of the Silk Road Fund
to specifically advance or finance the belt
and the road initiative.
Right.
So I remember Brad Setzer recently just
on the debate over the size of FX reserves,
Brad Setzer had a great piece of research
about the possibility that maybe China
has an additional $3 trillion, I think it was,
worth of assets that aren't necessarily
accounted for in official statistics.
The idea being that if it hadn't channeled so much of that money
into the Silk Road Fund or Belt and Road and programs
like that, this would be an available pool of cash
that it could use for other things.
What is the political appetite, I guess,
to move away from using that money to exert Chinese influence
in other parts of the world, buy up commodities,
things like that, build ports in Africa, whatever,
versus maybe starting to channel some of it more domestically.
No, Tracey, that's an excellent point.
Brad and I, we are colleagues.
And somehow we have done independent research
on similar topics and all that.
His research has always been brilliant and solid.
His charts are fantastic.
I would question the color coding aspect of it.
Oh, really?
Yeah.
But his charts are great.
My estimation of the size of shadow reserves or whatever,
the assets, the foreign exchange asset that
are not recorded on China's official foreign exchange
statistics, in the same proximity to breast estimate.
And in particular, for a lot of these asset managed
by state administration of foreign exchange,
it established domestic and international investment
corporations.
And my assessment of to what extent
this would be used to solve, to project power globally,
I would say perhaps in the current global geopolitical
environment, not so much.
And the reason is because this is perhaps
is another point where China's policymakers tend
to think differently in terms of economic or financial
management diversification.
It used to be the at least starting from 2007 to 2013.
During this period of time, the discussion
about diversification of foreign exchange reserves
has been diversified away from US treasuries
because the yield on US treasuries was so low
and the opportunity for us to hold most of our reserves
in US treasuries is so high.
Therefore, we need to diversify in strategic asset overseas,
such as critical minerals, oil gas, or some startup
companies and all that.
And a certain people even put out agenda in terms of,
these are the six areas that we need to think about
in terms of strategic asset.
But now diversification becomes a risk.
Because diversification cannot diversify away systemic risk,
and for China, at this moment, systemic risk
becomes being sanctioned by the West.
This is my assessment.
Obviously, I did not get this from Xi Jinping or anybody.
But given the West collective sanction against Russia,
especially the freeze of Russian reserves,
now you realize, well, who has the largest foreign exchange
reserves in the world?
Well, it's China.
And where are most of the reserve invested
or most of the assets invested or owned by sovereign funds?
There are most of the sovereign funds
investing in Europe and America.
There are not necessarily politically aligned
or geopolitically aligned in times
of geoeconomic contingency, such as Taiwan.
I think that's a very reasonable assumption.
You actually brought up something
that I wanted to ask you about as well,
which is China's buying of US treasuries.
And there is a sort of perpetual concern
that one day China is not going to be there
to finance the US deficit, I guess.
How realistic is that concern in an era
where China is potentially worried
about something like sanctions?
To be honest, I'm not surprised
that the appetite for China to slow down or buy less,
US treasuries has exist or has already happened.
Part of the reason is because the conversation
has already started in the 2000s.
And the people already realized,
well, there is opportunity cost of holding US treasuries.
At that time, the opportunity cost was purely
in terms of economic.
But now the problem becomes,
perhaps there is also geopolitical risk.
The diversification aspect of it.
And then the other aspect of the debate comes down to,
well, perhaps China would not necessarily
want to dump US treasuries in large amount too fast,
either because ultimately, any volatility
in US treasuries market,
or for that matter, the depreciation of US dollar
is going to inflict a huge pain
on the Chinese central bank's balance sheet as well.
So I just have one more question.
And this is going to be one of those questions
that's totally unfair because it's actually
like incredibly open-ended.
And we could probably do another hour on this,
but it's got to be like one question.
But the title of your book,
how the Communist Party of China,
sovereign funds, how the Communist Party
of China finances its global ambition.
We've been talking a lot about the financing.
But what are the global ambitions?
Like that?
This is actually another episode.
I know it's a whole other episode
because we are probably a whole series of like,
but I do think we should like touch on that.
Like how would you summarize the global ambitions
of the Chinese Communist Party?
I think the global ambitions have changed
and evolved over time.
It used to be the case that from things
shopping outward before up until 2013,
or the end of 2012,
the global ambition has been growing the economy,
raising up the people's life standard
and so that the party can stay in power.
And starting from 2013 and outward,
we started to see the,
there is an inflation of the party's ambition
from the Belt and Road Initiative
to the building of shared human destiny.
And a lot of these reside or resonates
with the current leader, President Xi Jinping's
continued search for great ideas.
And this brings me back to Deng Xiaoping.
Deng Xiaoping in this 1992 tour.
He said, it is okay for us to not have new ideas
as long as we do not change
with our economic reform and open up policy.
But right now, the ambition seems to be changing
and it seems to be a moving target
with regard to figuring out what exactly we are trying to do.
Well, I do think maybe we should,
at some point, have you back for like an hour,
just like how this is all changing
and where it's all going and how it's evolving.
A song and Zoe Lut,
this was a fascinating conversation.
Really appreciate you coming on up.
Thank you both for having me
and I'm a big fan.
Oh, thank you so much.
Thank you.
["Deng Xiaoping in China"]
Tracy, I thought that was great.
I need to come up with something like the four Ds of something.
Just like, I feel like a calling card,
some big thing is like, it's so good.
Well, I'm glad you asked that last question
about the ambitions of China
because I think it hints at the fundamental tension here,
which and Zoe mentioned this,
which is for years,
the party justified its control
by promising economic growth.
So you have that social contract,
but I think the difficulty now is
what if that control is coming
at the expense of economic growth?
You know, if we're talking about a lot of these difficulties
are in fact a political economy problem,
then I think it raises that question
and becomes extremely tricky for the party to actually navigate.
I hadn't really thought about that point before
about the sort of,
I guess I would say inherently decentralizing effect
of more household demand, right?
That at some level,
if households have more cash,
if they're less financially repressed, et cetera,
then at some level,
like there's a limit of the degree of control
that political leaders can have
about that spending and where it goes
and how that money is consumed.
I hadn't really,
I sort of had this conception
that will maybe for domestic industrial purposes,
you want to prioritize the interests of certain exporters
or certain industries,
but just the idea of an inherently decentralized effect
is one that I hadn't thought about at all.
Well, and also it highlights the importance
of the public business entities in China.
And this is something that I only realized
from actually spending time in Beijing,
which is a lot of countries have big government buildings
or monuments of some sort.
A lot of the biggest buildings in Beijing are the CIC
and the other sort of state-owned enterprises.
And if you walk around the ring roads of Beijing,
you get a real sense of their sort of monumental importance
to the economy.
There is physical evidence of it,
which you can't really appreciate
unless you see them.
The other thing that I thought was really interesting
was the idea of more need for diversification
in order to offset the decoupling aspect
that Zoe talked about.
But again, in times like this,
where you need more money to support the domestic economy,
but at the same time,
you're worried about the external environment
and you want to diversify away from the US
to sort of offset that.
That also seems really difficult to do.
So many interesting things.
Also, can I just say,
I am now I'm slightly obsessed with idiot melons seeds
and I'm gonna go off and research.
That's what I'm doing.
I'm sure you're gonna get off, I guess.
I was gonna do the same thing.
Yes, excellent.
All right, shall we leave it there?
Let's leave it there.
Okay, this has been another episode
of the Odd Lots podcast.
I'm Tracy Alloway.
You can follow me at Tracy Alloway.
And I'm Joe Weisenthal.
You can follow me at the stalwart.
Follow our guest, Songwen Zoe Lu.
At that same name, Songwen Zoe Lu.
Follow our producers,
Carmen Rodriguez at Carmen Armin
and Dashal Bennett at Dashbot.
And check out all of the Bloomberg podcasts
under the handle at podcasts.
And for more Odd Lots content,
go to bloomberg.com slash Odd Lots.
We post transcripts, we have a blog,
and a newsletter that comes out every Friday.
And, and before I forget,
we also have a discord.
It's really fun.
24 or seven listeners like yourself
are in there chatting about all these topics,
economics, macro stuff, currencies,
super interesting plays, discord.gg slash Odd Lots.
And if you enjoy Odd Lots,
if you like these conversations,
then please leave us a positive review
on your favorite podcast platform.
Thanks for listening.