Welcome to What Happens Next.
My name is Larry Bernstein.
What happens next is a podcast
which covers economics, finance, and politics.
Today's special episode is entitled,
Run on the Banks.
Our guest today is Nicholas Farron,
who is a senior fellow at the Broglie Institute in Brussels
and at the Peterson Institute in Washington, DC.
His research focuses on the financial system
and international banking regulatory matters.
Today, Nicholas will discuss the radical change
in US policy for uninsured bank deposits.
There is much to cover, so buckle up.
I make this podcast to learn and I offer it free of charge.
If you enjoyed his podcast,
please subscribe from our website for weekly emails
so that you can continue to enjoy this content.
Let's begin with Nicholas's six minute opening remarks.
So maybe I can set the scene with what happened and why
and what we should expect.
So what happened is Silicon Valley Bank was closed
on Friday, March 10th and taken over by the FDIC
and by then the expectation was
that the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
would do it by the book.
They would tell us, said they would reimburse
insured depositors as early as Monday morning
and then the rest of the insured deposits,
probably a small haircut.
And then during the weekend, they said,
oh, by the way, we're providing a lot of liquidity
to the banking sector on very generous terms,
that's a bank term funding facility,
but even more significant, we're actually going
to guarantee deposits of Silicon Valley Bank
and also have signature bank for that matter
without any limit.
Silicon Valley Bank is a bank
where there were very, very large depositors.
I still haven't completely figured out
if some of them were above a billion dollars, I think so.
That's a lot of money.
So that was the action.
I'm leaving aside the term facility,
but I'm focusing on the unlimited guarantee of deposits.
So why did they do that?
That's a difficult question to answer.
There was a big article of the Financial Times
early in the week.
And to me, it's difficult to understand the decision
purely from a standpoint of financial stability
and avoiding contagion.
So I think a big driver of the decision
was actually to rescue Silicon Valley.
You can call it a bailout if you want,
but it's not a bailout of the bank
or for that matter of the banking sector,
it's really a bailout of Silicon Valley.
So when President Biden says shareholders
weren't bailed out, that's actually not true.
It is true that shareholders of Silicon Valley Bank
were not bailed out, that's absolutely true.
But shareholders of a number of Silicon Valley startups
and a lot of limited partners
of a lot of Silicon Valley venture capital funds
were bailed out.
They would have lost their money,
they didn't lose their money
because of this extraordinary intervention
of the federal authorities.
And what they did is they invoked the systemic risk exemption,
which was really to say,
if we don't do that support action,
the whole economy and financial system
are going down the tubes.
I think the short answer to why they did it
is to rescue Silicon Valley.
That may be a legitimate objective we can discuss,
but from a strict financial stability perspective,
they didn't have to do that.
Now, the implications of course are vast and unknown.
It's in my view, a regime change in US banking
because I don't see how you can put the proverbial
two spaced back in the tube.
Once you've said, this is a bank that's not so big,
signature bank is even smaller.
The financial conditions before Friday,
March of 10s were pretty orderly,
no particular turmoil.
So you have a medium-sized bank that fails
in orderly conditions, you say, oh, systemic risk.
So that means you will do it all the time.
I really cannot see how that decision can be reversed.
And therefore, my contention is that there has been
for 90 years this regime of limited deposit insurance,
and I think it's over.
So it's a massive change for the United States.
Important to know this is specific to the United States
because in other jurisdictions, deposits are guaranteed
without limits anyway.
I mean, that's not the letter of the law,
it varies across jurisdictions,
but there are very few cases,
there are a few cases in Denmark here and there,
but there are very few cases where you have
the kind of market disciplines that had existed
in the US until now, where deposits were not essentially
fully guaranteed by the government.
We saw Cyprus, but the government was broke,
there have been other examples like that in emerging markets.
But in economies where the government is not broke,
normally the guarantee of full deposits
was basically as good as the government credit itself.
The US was an exception, it has a lot to do with the fact
that the US is much less of a bank-based economy,
much more of a capital markets-based economy
than other parts of the world.
And I think one of the biggest questions is,
will that be reversed?
Will that decision with the US become more bank-based,
less capital markets-based?
So my view is there are very profound implications,
where at the beginning of a learning curve,
that's a big deal.
Do you think adults could disagree
about the state of the financial system,
namely that you think that system is robust
and could handle financial runs,
while others might think that it is unstable and could not?
And how was the Fed unaware that Silicon Valley Bank
had huge losses on its investment portfolio?
We'll know more as the Fed has commissioned
the forensic analysis of its Silicon Valley Bank,
the professor of failure.
We can discuss the exact drivers.
It's not all down to the relaxation of rules
under the Trump administration,
because even under a lax rule,
this was a bank that was supervised by the Fed,
and the Fed had to make sure it had a viable business model.
I'm all for blaming the Trump administration
for examining Silicon Valley Bank and the likes
from a number of ratios and enhanced
prudential regulation or whatever it's called,
but that doesn't exonerate the Fed
from its supervisory failure.
Silicon Valley Bank had two unique attributes
to its balance sheet.
On the asset side, it had enormous positions
in long-dated agency and treasury bonds
that it did not hedge the interest rate risk,
and lost substantial sums when interest rates went up.
And second, on the liability side,
it had mammoth deposits from very few accounts,
and this was fast money that could leave the bank
on a moment's notice.
So you got funding risky long-dated assets
with overnight deposits, which seems like lunacy.
And I'm not sure you can blame the Trump administration,
because the losses on the bond portfolio
only happened recently in the past year
during the Biden administration
when the Fed started raising interest rates.
The Fed looks bad.
Let's make it clear this is a supervisory failure.
The Fed didn't do what it was supposed to do,
and the only thing we have to ask is why,
but we know the what.
The what is a supervisory failure?
No way to sugarcoat it.
Next topic is why did the Fed Treasury FDIC
decide to protect all the uninsured creditors
of Silicon Valley Bank?
As you said, the risk of system-wide contagion
did not seem catastrophic.
And you can always guarantee deposits of the other banks
after the first bank failure that had losses on its deposits
to prevent future moral hazard.
Why do you think Silicon Valley is considered
to be so vulnerable and required financial support
in this way?
And do you think that this may be related
to Silicon Valley's political contributions
to the Democrats?
I didn't say Silicon Valley used its power.
I think that's a plausible assumption,
but that's not what I said.
There are people who think that Silicon Valley
is super important for the nation
and cannot be allowed to fail
because it's a national treasure,
the national security community.
A lot of Silicon Valley startups do business
with the Pentagon, with the intelligence community.
Therefore, you could imagine political motivations
to rescue Silicon Valley that don't boil down
to political power, lobbying, political influence,
the nations and things like that.
The Silicon Valley greater community
had an aggregate $200 billion of deposits
with Silicon Valley bank.
The chatter was that these uninsured deposits
would likely get back at least 80 cents on the dollar.
The Fed could have said we're gonna give you
a 50 cents of cash right now and more
depending on the proceeds after we look at the bank.
The total losses we're talking about here
are 20 to 40 billion dollars, which is peanuts.
This is the change in the equity market value
of Amazon stock every hour.
Why do we feel the need to protect the wealthiest Americans
from any losses after they made an error
in financial judgment?
And also non-Americans,
which is a political point of contention.
I don't disagree with any of this.
I just don't want to jump to conclusions.
Now, the counter argument to that,
you said either can disagree.
The counter argument to that is
the corporate deposit run
was much faster than anybody expected.
46 billion dollars or whatever it was in less than 24 hours.
We discovered something new that we didn't know,
which is that this kind of France
is more powerful, faster, larger, scarier
than any of us believed.
It's a new era.
You can move money with a click on your smartphone.
You technology, none of that had been unspaded.
It's not your grandmother's bank run.
And therefore the old playbook didn't apply.
In 2009, a relatively junior finance minister
in the Irish government announced
that Ireland would fully guarantee
all the deposits of the Irish banking system.
And within minutes, there was a huge sucking sound
and all the deposits started leaving
the other major European banks and headed to Ireland.
So we have seen this before.
And as part of Dodd-Frank,
we had this dual class banking system.
The largest, systemically important banks
had their deposits fully insured,
but not mid-sized banks, like Silicon Valley Bank.
Their big deposits are not.
So there's no reason why you should hold your deposit
at Silicon Valley Bank when you can hold them
at JPMorgan and be risk free.
Maybe you're in a little less interest,
maybe you get inferior service,
but my God, you don't lose your money.
And I think that's exactly the argument that can
and has been made to justify the invocation
of the systemic risk exemption,
which is the system was less stable than we thought it was.
If we hadn't invoked that exemption,
we would have had a massive run from all the regionals
and maybe also community banks.
And that would have been unmanageable.
We would have had a number of shotgun marriages
and things like that.
The Fed would have had to provide generously,
equity the way it did anyway, no matter what.
So for me, the kind of playbook answer during the weekend
should have included the announcement of something
like the bank term funding program,
maybe a bit less generous.
We can debate that.
I'm unconvinced it had to include a limited deposit guarantee.
I think it's the fact that we would have seen
more deposits moving and running.
We would have seen probably a number of regional banks,
more than just first Republic being the target
of shotgun acquisitions.
So it would have been more bumpy.
It would have been less orderly
than what we observed in the last few days.
I think that's a fact.
My contention is it would have been manageable.
The US banking system would have been transformed
by the episode, but not as fundamentally
as it has been transformed by the abandonment
of limited deposit guarantees.
That would be my way of looking at it.
Walter Baggett said in the mid 19th century
that it is the role of the central bank
to provide the liquidity in a banking crisis
by providing loans against good collateral
at a discount to market value with a penalty interest rate.
And here, the Fed is offering to lend money
against collateral not at a discount,
but at its original cost and at a lower interest rate
for term with no mark to market provision.
This runs against the rules of central banking.
Yes and no.
I mean, there have been other examples
of poorly collateralized emergency liquidity assistance.
Cyprus was a notorious example.
There have been examples of favorable lending operations
of the ECB, which many people think have been successful.
My impression is that the bank term funding facility
announced on March 12 as particularly generous,
maybe too generous.
There is a reasonable debate to be had,
but I view it as less fundamental a chance
and the unlimited deposit guarantee,
because that's something for the nerds, right?
I mean, it's something that the Fed does now.
It's not really obliged to do it the same way the next time.
I know the Fed did not say that we're guaranteeing
all uninsured deposits forever, but who would not think that?
I think it will be basically impossible
to reverse in practice.
So I think that's why I've called it a regime change.
Who made the decision to abandon the playbook
and ensure all deposits?
Was this like that junior treasury official in Ireland
in 2009 who nearly bankrupted the country?
It's pretty clear that the decision involved
the political level and probably also weighed
to the White House.
At this point, we don't know exactly how that decision
was made and what arguments were weighed
and who advocated what position.
I would imagine the FDIC didn't advocate the plan
that was adopted based on their historical stance.
Let's go back to your metaphor
about putting the toothpaste back in the tube.
Congress may not want to guarantee
all the deposits going forward.
Will they choose to prevent treasury
from guaranteeing deposits even in a systemic crisis
to persuade the market to go back
to the previous uninsured deposit regime?
I'd expect you're right.
I'm not sure how explicit it has to be.
So if you want to reverse it,
probably you need a number of people
to fall on their swords because that means you're saying
the decisions that was made was a wrong call.
And that has consequences.
I don't know whether it's possible to do that.
I don't think you can say, oops, we made the wrong call
but everything goes on as before.
What I hear in Congress is not really,
we need to defend market discipline.
It's more like some banks have been told
they have this guarantee and others haven't
and that's unfair, which is not exactly the same message.
The likely direction of policy will be effectively
everybody's guaranteed, but how that will be formulated,
I don't know.
And if you think the situation is stable,
you could leave it at that.
The interesting thing is what happened
when another bank fails and it depends
which bank it is, right?
So can you invoke the systemic risk exception
that fits a very tiny small-town bank in the middle of nowhere?
You tell me, I mean, I think this perception
that the limited deposit insurance now is a complete fiction
is now a very reasonable way to look at things.
I think it will become entrenched
but I'm not sure you need legislation for that.
I suspect that Congress will demand
that if all deposits are insured,
that they will require increasing regulation
and that banks reduce the risk of their balance sheets.
We're not going to allow banks to take risk
and earn a big return for their shareholders
if the US Treasury take the downside
and equity holders get all the upside.
I also do not think that banks will be allowed
to take interest rate risk going forward.
They can only take some credit risk within strict limits.
I'm not sure how you can say the banks
don't hold interest rate risk, right?
You want them to hold high-quality liquid assets.
That's part of the framework action.
They would be required to hedge their interest rate risk
using derivatives.
Yeah, is it really possible to hedge
an entire bank's balance sheet?
I mean, it's a very yes, but in practice, I don't know.
As a professional fixed income specialist,
I could have managed Silicon Valley's bank's interest rate
exposure and it would not have been fully infringed
on my podcast work.
Going back to your opening remarks
and your comment that Europe is a banking led system
and the US is a capital markets funded system.
And you suggested that America will be moving
in the direction of funding more with banks
and less with the capital markets.
I want to push back on this idea.
I think banks will face new onerous capital
and regulatory requirements that will make it
even more difficult for banks to invest
in long-term risky assets.
The capital markets will be more competitive
to purchase assets.
This means that there will be ever greater
securitization of loans that are sold
to non-bank institutions.
Maybe we'll see.
My model for the decision, and maybe I'm completely wrong,
is this was a rescue of Silicon Valley.
Silicon Valley is too important to fail for whatever reason
you mentioned political donations.
I mentioned national security, maybe it's something different.
But the point was we don't want a gigantic cycle
in Silicon Valley.
We're becoming a bit Chinese, right?
I mean, that's exactly what the Chinese government did in 2015
about its equity markets.
We haven't done that for equity markets,
but basically when President Biden commented the decision
by saying, this is how capitalism works,
my reaction was, no, actually it isn't.
Capitalism is people taking risks,
and that includes venture capitalists
and very wealthy individuals and startups.
And if this grew up by leaving too much money
in a single bank account, which is not insured,
they learn from their mistakes.
So I think there is a profound question
to which I don't have the answer,
which is what does this action reveal
about where the US is right now,
and what are the fundamentals of the US system?
And certainly looked at from outside of the US,
this is a question that jumps out of the situation
we're observing.
I'm not sure Biden's views reflect his administration,
the Congress, or the country.
I think it might be a simple message
to remain calm and not much else.
Yeah, well, he had to say that this is normal.
And of course we know it's not a full story
because the losses will be borne by the banking system
through special assessments of the FDIC,
and that costs one way or another
will be passed on to the economy.
So strictly speaking, of course, his rights,
there is no tax-perism on yet stake
unless the government has to rescue the FDIC,
but we are not there at this point.
His words were, broadly, correct.
But that's not the economic reality
of what has been decided, and I suspect
nobody misses that point.
The largest banks in the United States
announced on Thursday, March 17th
that they were making $30 billion of deposits
in First Republic Bank.
When the stock was halted initially,
my expectation was that one or more banks
would put in equity in First Republic.
Instead, the banking group invested
in four-month senior debt claims,
which was not exactly a resounding support
to improve the quality of the capital structure of the bank.
Who thought this would be a meaningful solution
to the bank run, or that it would improve
the capital structure?
I have no idea.
I'm at the loss.
I don't get it.
Did the banks meet with Treasury,
and did the government ask them to put in equity,
and did they counter with debt
that would be guaranteed by the US government?
I've never worked in the US government.
I've worked for two and a half years
in the French government,
and that was a very, very long time ago.
But that's my government experience.
What I learned is from the inside,
governing looks much messier and more chaotic
than from the outside.
And that's much more the case
when you're in a situation of crisis,
or turmoil, or volatility, or uncertainty,
or whatever you call it,
than on a day-to-day basis.
But actually, when you're in government,
it feels like crisis every day,
if you're at the senior enough level of government, at least.
So, I could easily imagine that inner workings
of this decision-making process,
both during the weekend,
leading to the full deposit guarantee,
and during the week leading to this transaction,
assuming, as you do, and as I do choose it,
there was some governance input into the transaction,
probably there was a lot of chaotic back-and-forth.
Maybe one day we'll learn the details, maybe not.
We abandoned our 90-year history
that FDR initiated of ensuring deposits up to a limit.
That regime is over.
What does the new, new deal look like,
and is it meaningfully different?
So, my gut tells me it's important.
I cannot imagine it being without consequence.
So, US has had this limited deposit guarantee,
not far from a century,
and basically nobody else has had that.
I mean, there are a number of jurisdictions, as you know,
which have introduced limited deposit guarantee
in the statute book,
but they have never really implemented in practice.
And so, your zone is a good example of that.
Japan is a good example of that.
So, the US was a place where the limited deposit guarantee
not only existed on paper,
but actually was implemented that way.
I mean, with variations, and we know that in 2008,
there was a suspension of most of it,
but you look at the practice of the FDIC over the decades,
and you know, there has been a kind of drum beat
of small banks being resolved
with uninsured depositors losing some money,
generally not a lot, but some of the money.
And that meant it was not just a method, it was a reality.
So, let's assume that's over.
What does that mean?
It will mean the US becoming a bit more like
the other jurisdictions, more bank-based,
let's kept on market space.
But maybe I'm wrong about this.
It's a giant experiment, we don't know.
I think it's probably going to be transformational.
It means less market discipline, that's a fact.
I think it's undeniable.
Let's examine the European experience.
Ireland guaranteed its country's bank deposits,
and it almost bankrupted the sovereign.
It took two years for people to realize it,
but to its credit, the IMF understood it very early.
Iceland recognized immediately
that it could not guarantee its bank deposits
because it could not afford it.
Switzerland's banks are also too big relative to its size.
In most countries, there is no such thing
as an uninsured deposits.
Things are yours on, right?
It has gone through a gigantic crisis.
Greece has defaulted Cyprus,
which was basically broke.
A number of countries have had to go to the IMF,
we had capital controls, we had a number of bank failures.
Has a single depositor lost money outside of Cyprus?
I'm not aware of that.
So yes, it did in Cyprus,
but that was basically a sovereign event.
What are you optimistic about as it relates
to the US banking system?
I hope that we will see a sense of accountability
in the supervisory frameworks that will prevent it
having to go through structural change.
So I think the Fed has convinced us
that yes, it screwed up,
but it's able to learn from the lessons.
I think we're going to see a number
of good US institutions in action.
There's a lot of posturing in Congress,
but congressional hearings can also be very useful.
I hope we'll all see genuine policy debate,
hopefully resulting in better policies.
As a final follow-up question,
the systemic banks must capitalize their losses
on their held maturity investments,
and the mid-sized banks do not.
I assume that will have to change.
I also suspect that capital requirements in banks
will increase and that market accounting
will be required even for hard-to-value assets.
You know, wait, it's an impossible equation, right?
I mean, you want to mark bank balances to markets,
but you don't want to mark their regulatory requirements
to market because that would be insanely procyclical.
So there are no really comprehensive solution
to that challenge and you have to find the least bad compromise.
Some of it has to be supervision.
We need buffers, we need discretion
in the hands of the supervisor,
because I don't think you can encapsulate
a perfect formula, a perfect sense of mechanical incentives
that will keep banks sound.
So the banking sector is neither really public nor private.
It will remain that way.
It's as old as finance and finance is several thousand years old.
So I don't expect these contradictions
to be fully resolved because I don't think that's possible.
But maybe we can avoid the same mistakes
being made in the same way again.
Thanks, Nicholas Varen, for joining us today.
If you missed this week's show,
Parents, Paying for the Party, check it out.
Our guest was Laura Hamilton,
who is a sociologist at the University of California,
Merced, and the author of multiple books,
including Broke, Who is Paying for the Party
and Parenting by Degree.
Laura is interested in how socioeconomic status
influences who goes to college,
how students perform, their job prospects,
and their marriage market.
Last week's show was on the opioid crisis.
Our speaker was Gerald Posner, who wrote the book,
Pharma, Greed, Lies, and the Poisoning of America.
Gerald spoke about the conflict that pharmaceutical firms face
with her desire for advancing public health
and maximizing profits.
We will also discuss the advancement of pain management care,
fears of addiction, and the success and failures of Oxycod.
I would not like to make a plug for next week's show
with Dan Willingham, who is a professor of cognitive psychology
at the University of Virginia.
He is the author of the new book entitled,
Outsmarcher Brain, Why Learning Is Hard
and How You Can Make It Easy.
You can find our previous episodes and transcripts
on our website, what happens next in sixminutes.com.
If you enjoy today's podcast,
please subscribe to our weekly emails
and follow us on Apple Podcasts or Spotify.
I would like to thank our audience
for your continued engagement
with these important issues.
Goodbye.
.